Skip to main content
Social Sci LibreTexts

8.6: Consumption Taxes as a Reason for Trade

  • Page ID
    40906
    • Anonymous
    • LibreTexts
    \( \newcommand{\vecs}[1]{\overset { \scriptstyle \rightharpoonup} {\mathbf{#1}} } \) \( \newcommand{\vecd}[1]{\overset{-\!-\!\rightharpoonup}{\vphantom{a}\smash {#1}}} \)\(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\)\(\newcommand{\AA}{\unicode[.8,0]{x212B}}\)

    Learning Objectives
    1. Describe the price, quantity, and trade effects of a domestic consumption tax implemented by a small open economy.

    This section will show how a consumption tax can cause trade for a small, perfectly competitive, open economy. In other words, even if countries were identical with respect to their resource endowments, their technology, and their preferences and even if there were no economies of scale or imperfectly competitive markets, a purely domestic policy, such as a consumption tax, can induce trade between countries.

    Consider a small open economy with a perfectly competitive industry. Let the domestic market be represented by the supply and demand curves in Figure \(\PageIndex{1}\). Suppose initially that free trade is allowed with the rest of the world, but by coincidence (actually by assumption), let the free trade price be exactly equal to the autarky price for the good. This is shown as the price, \(P_{FT}\). At that price, both supply and demand equal \(Q_1\), and thus no imports or exports occur, even though there is free trade.

    Figure8-6-1.png
    Figure \(\PageIndex{1}\): Inducing Exports with a Domestic Consumption Subsidy

    Next, suppose that the government of this country imposes a specific (per unit) consumption tax on this product. Let the tax rate be set at “\(t\).” This means the government will collect “\(t\)” dollars for every unit of the good sold in the domestic market, regardless of whether the product is produced domestically or imported.

    The tax will raise the domestic consumer price of the good by the full amount of the tax to \(P_C\) and reduce domestic demand to \(Q_2\). Domestic producers will not be affected by the consumption tax since continued competition in free trade with firms in the rest of the world will allow them to continue to charge the world price of \(P_{FT}\). Note that in a closed economy, the producers would absorb some of the tax burden by lowering their price so as to maintain the profit maximum. However, being open to trade implies that the country can purchase as much as it likes at the world price. This means that the producer price \(P_P\) will remain equal to the free trade price \(P_{FT}\), and the full burden of the tax falls on consumers. Thus \(P_C = P_{FT} + t\) and \(P_P = P_{FT}\).

    Since the tax has no effect on the producer price but raises the consumer price, domestic demand falls to \(Q_2\) while domestic supply remains at \(Q_1\). The difference, \(Q_1 − Q_2\) (the length of the red line), represents the amount exported to the rest of the world. This implies that the consumption tax will induce exports of the good. Thus this is an example in which a domestic policy (a consumption tax) can cause trade (i.e., exports) to occur.

    Key Takeaways

    • A consumption tax raises the price paid by consumers by the full amount of the tax when the country is open to international trade.
    • A consumption tax has no effect on the price paid by producers when the country is open to international trade.
    • A consumption tax causes exports when implemented by a small country open to trade but not initially trading.
    Exercise \(\PageIndex{1}\)
    1. Jeopardy Questions. As in the popular television game show, you are given an answer to a question and you must respond with the question. For example, if the answer is “a tax on imports,” then the correct question is “What is a tariff?”
      1. Of increase, decrease, or stay the same, the effect on the price consumers pay for a good when the government sets a domestic consumption tax in a freely trading economy.
      2. Of exports or imports, the one that is likely to be increased as a result of a domestic consumption tax on that product.
      3. Of increase, decrease, or stay the same, the effect on the price producers receive for a good when the government sets a domestic consumption tax in a freely trading economy.

    This page titled 8.6: Consumption Taxes as a Reason for Trade is shared under a CC BY-NC-SA license and was authored, remixed, and/or curated by Anonymous via source content that was edited to the style and standards of the LibreTexts platform; a detailed edit history is available upon request.