Skip to main content
Social Sci LibreTexts

6.4: Labor-Leisure Choices

  • Page ID
    4081
  • \( \newcommand{\vecs}[1]{\overset { \scriptstyle \rightharpoonup} {\mathbf{#1}} } \) \( \newcommand{\vecd}[1]{\overset{-\!-\!\rightharpoonup}{\vphantom{a}\smash {#1}}} \)\(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\)\(\newcommand{\AA}{\unicode[.8,0]{x212B}}\)

    Learning Objectives
    • Interpret labor-leisure budget constraint graphs
    • Predict consumer choices based on wages and other compensation
    • Explain the backward-bending supply curve of labor

    People do not obtain utility just from products they purchase. They also obtain utility from leisure time. Leisure time is time not spent at work. The decision-making process of a utility-maximizing household applies to what quantity of hours to work in much the same way that it applies to purchases of goods and services. Choices made along the labor-leisure budget constraint, as wages shift, provide the logical underpinning for the labor supply curve. The discussion also offers some insights about the range of possible reactions when people receive higher wages, and specifically about the claim that if people are paid higher wages, they will work a greater quantity of hours—assuming that they have a say in the matter.

    According to the Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. workers averaged \(38.6\) hours per week on the job in 2014. This average includes part-time workers; for full-time workers only, the average was \(42.5\) hours per week. Table \(\PageIndex{1}\) shows that more than half of all workers are on the job \(35\) to \(48\) hours per week, but significant proportions work more or less than this amount.

    Table \(\PageIndex{2}\) breaks down the average hourly compensation received by private industry workers, including wages and benefits. Wages and salaries are about three-quarters of total compensation received by workers; the rest is in the form of health insurance, vacation pay, and other benefits. The compensation workers receive differs for many reasons, including experience, education, skill, talent, membership in a labor union, and the presence of discrimination against certain groups in the labor market. Issues surrounding the inequality of incomes in a market-oriented economy are explored in the chapters on Poverty and Economic Inequality and Issues in Labor Markets: Unions, Discrimination, Immigration. Table \(\PageIndex{1}\): Persons at Work, by Average Hours Worked per Week in 2013 (Total number of workers: 137.7 million)(Source: http://www.bls.gov/news.release/empsit.t18.htm)
    Hours Worked per Week Number of Workers Percentage of Workforce
    1–14 hours 6.9 million 5.0%
    15–34 hours 27.6 million 20.1%
    35–40 hours 68.5 million 49.9%
    41–48 hours 11.9 million 8.6%
    49–59 hours 13.3 million 9.6%
    60 hours and over 9.3 million 6.8%
    Table \(\PageIndex{2}\): Hourly Compensation: Wages, Benefits, and Taxes in 2014(Source: http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/ecec.pdf)
    Compensation, Wage, Salary, and Benefits $30.92 per hour
    Wages and Salaries $20.92
    Benefits  
    Vacation $2.09
    Supplemental Pay $0.84
    Insurance $2.15
    Health Benefits $2.36
    Retirement and Savings $1.24
    Defined Benefit $0.57
    Defined Contribution $0.064
    Legally Required $2.46

    The Labor-Leisure Budget Constraint

    How do workers make decisions about the number of hours to work? Again, let’s proceed with a concrete example. The economic logic is precisely the same as in the case of a consumption choice budget constraint, but the labels are different on a labor-leisure budget constraint.

    Vivian has \(70\) hours per week that she could devote either to work or to leisure, and her wage is \(\$10\)/hour. The lower budget constraint in Figure \(\PageIndex{1}\) shows Vivian’s possible choices. The horizontal axis of this diagram measures both leisure and labor, by showing how Vivian’s time is divided between leisure and labor. Hours of leisure are measured from left to right on the horizontal axis, while hours of labor are measured from right to left. Vivian will compare choices along this budget constraint, ranging from \(70\) hours of leisure and no income at point \(S\) to zero hours of leisure and \(\$700\) of income at point \(L\). She will choose the point that provides her with the highest total utility. For this example, let’s assume that Vivian’s utility-maximizing choice occurs at \(O\), with \(30\) hours of leisure, \(40\) hours of work, and \(\$400\) in weekly income.

    How a Rise in Wages Alters the Utility-Maximizing Choice

    The graph shows how raised wages can influence the opportunity set.
    Figure \(\PageIndex{1}\): Vivian’s original choice is point \(O\) on the lower opportunity set. A rise in her wage causes her opportunity set to swing upward. In response to the increase in wages, Vivian can make a range of different choices available to her: a choice like \(D\), which involves less work; and a choice like \(B\), which involves the same amount of work but more income; or a choice like \(A\), which involves more work and considerably more income. Vivian’s personal preferences will determine which choice she makes.

    For Vivian to discover the labor-leisure choice that will maximize her utility, she does not have to place numerical values on the total and marginal utility that she would receive from every level of income and leisure. All that really matters is that Vivian can compare, in her own mind, whether she would prefer more leisure or more income, given the tradeoffs she faces. If Vivian can say to herself: “I’d really rather work a little less and have more leisure, even if it means less income,” or “I’d be willing to work more hours to make some extra income,” then as she gradually moves in the direction of her preferences, she will seek out the utility-maximizing choice on her labor-leisure budget constraint.

    Now imagine that Vivian’s wage level increases to \(\$12\)/hour. A higher wage will mean a new budget constraint that tilts up more steeply; conversely, a lower wage would have led to a new budget constraint that was flatter. How will a change in the wage and the corresponding shift in the budget constraint affect Vivian’s decisions about how many hours to work?

    Vivian’s choices of quantity of hours to work and income along her new budget constraint can be divided into several categories, using the dashed horizontal and vertical lines in Figure \(\PageIndex{1}\) that go through her original choice (\(O\)). One set of choices in the upper-left portion of the new budget constraint involves more hours of work (that is, less leisure) and more income, at a point like \(A\) with \(20\) hours of leisure, \(50\) hours of work, and \(\$600\) of income (that is, \(50\) hours of work multiplied by the new wage of \(\$12\) per hour). A second choice would be to work exactly the same \(40\) hours, and to take the benefits of the higher wage in the form of income that would now be \(\$480\), at choice \(B\). A third choice would involve more leisure and the same income at point \(C\) (that is, \(33-1/3\) hours of work multiplied by the new wage of \(\$12\) per hour equals \(\$400\) of total income). A fourth choice would involve less income and much more leisure at a point like \(D\), with a choice like \(50\) hours of leisure, \(20\) hours of work, and \(\$240\) in income.

    In effect, Vivian can choose whether to receive the benefits of her wage increase in the form of more income, or more leisure, or some mixture of these two. With this range of possibilities, it would be unwise to assume that Vivian (or anyone else) will necessarily react to a wage increase by working substantially more hours. Maybe they will; maybe they will not.

    Applications of Utility Maximizing with the Labor-Leisure Budget Constraint

    The theoretical insight that higher wages will sometimes cause an increase in hours worked, sometimes cause hours worked not to change by much, and sometimes cause hours worked to decline, has led to labor supply curves that look like the one in Figure \(\PageIndex{2}\). The bottom-left portion of the labor supply curve slopes upward, which reflects the situation of a person who reacts to a higher wage by supplying a greater quantity of labor. The middle, close-to-vertical portion of the labor supply curve reflects the situation of a person who reacts to a higher wage by supplying about the same quantity of labor. The very top portion of the labor supply curve is called a backward-bending supply curve for labor, which is the situation of high-wage people who can earn so much that they respond to a still-higher wage by working fewer hours. Read the following Clear It Up feature for more on the number of hours the average person works each year.

    A Backward-Bending Supply Curve of Labor

    The graph shows that the labor-leisure budget constraint can be influenced in several ways based on higher wages and the numbers of hours worked.
    Figure \(\PageIndex{2}\): The bottom upward-sloping portion of the labor supply curve shows that as wages increase over this range, the quantity of hours worked also increases. The middle, nearly vertical portion of the labor supply curve shows that as wages increase over this range, the quantity of hours worked changes very little. The backward-bending portion of the labor supply curve at the top shows that as wages increase over this range, the quantity of hours worked actually decreases. All three of these possibilities can be derived from how a change in wages causes movement in the labor-leisure budget constraint, and thus different choices by individuals.
    Example \(\PageIndex{1}\): Is America a nation of workaholics?

    Americans work a lot. Table \(\PageIndex{3}\) shows average hours worked per year in the United States, Canada, Japan, and several European countries, with data from 2013. To get a perspective on these numbers, someone who works \(40\) hours per week for \(50\) weeks per year, with two weeks off, would work \(2,000\) hours per year. The gap in hours worked is a little astonishing; the \(250\) to \(300\) hour gap between how much Americans work and how much Germans or the French work amounts to roughly six to seven weeks less of work per year. Economists who study these international patterns debate the extent to which average Americans and Japanese have a preference for working more than, say, Germans, or whether German workers and employers face particular kinds of taxes and regulations that lead to fewer hours worked. Many countries have laws that regulate the work week and dictate holidays and the standards of “normal” vacation time vary from country to country. It is also interesting to take the amount of time spent working in context; it is estimated that in the late nineteenth century in the United States, the average work week was over 60 hours per week—leaving little to no time for leisure.

    Table \(\PageIndex{3}\): Average Hours Worked Per Year in Select Countries(Source: stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=ANHRS)
    Country Average Annual Hours Actually Worked per Employed Person
    United States 1,824
    Spain 1,799
    Japan 1,759
    Canada 1,751
    United Kingdom 1,669
    Sweden 1,585
    Germany 1,443
    France 1,441

    The different responses to a rise in wages—more hours worked, the same hours worked, or fewer hours worked—are patterns exhibited by different groups of workers in the U.S. economy. Many full-time workers have jobs where the number of hours is held relatively fixed, partly by their own choice and partly by their employer’s practices. These workers do not much change their hours worked as wages rise or fall, so their supply curve of labor is inelastic. However, part-time workers and younger workers tend to be more flexible in their hours, and more ready to increase hours worked when wages are high or cut back when wages fall.

    The backward-bending supply curve for labor, when workers react to higher wages by working fewer hours and having more income, is not observed often in the short run. However, some well-paid professionals, like dentists or accountants, may react to higher wages by choosing to limit the number of hours, perhaps by taking especially long vacations, or taking every other Friday off. Over a long-term perspective, the backward-bending supply curve for labor is common. Over the last century, Americans have reacted to gradually rising wages by working fewer hours; for example, the length of the average work-week has fallen from about 60 hours per week in 1900 to the present average of less than \(40\) hours per week.

    Recognizing that workers have a range of possible reactions to a change in wages casts some fresh insight on a perennial political debate: the claim that a reduction in income taxes—which would, in effect, allow people to earn more per hour—will encourage people to work more. The leisure-income budget set points out that this connection will not hold true for all workers. Some people, especially part-timers, may react to higher wages by working more. Many will work the same number of hours. Some people, especially those whose incomes are already high, may react to the tax cut by working fewer hours. Of course, cutting taxes may be a good or a bad idea for a variety of reasons, not just because of its impact on work incentives, but the specific claim that tax cuts will lead people to work more hours is only likely to hold for specific groups of workers and will depend on how and for whom taxes are cut.

    Key Concepts and Summary

    When making a choice along the labor-leisure budget constraint, a household will choose the combination of labor, leisure, and income that provides the most utility. The result of a change in wage levels can be higher work hours, the same work hours, or lower work hours.

    Glossary

    backward-bending supply curve for labor
    the situation when high-wage people can earn so much that they respond to a still-higher wage by working fewer hours

    This page titled 6.4: Labor-Leisure Choices is shared under a CC BY 4.0 license and was authored, remixed, and/or curated by OpenStax via source content that was edited to the style and standards of the LibreTexts platform; a detailed edit history is available upon request.