Skip to main content
Social Sci LibreTexts

6.4: Applications of indifference analysis

  • Page ID
    108395
  • \( \newcommand{\vecs}[1]{\overset { \scriptstyle \rightharpoonup} {\mathbf{#1}} } \) \( \newcommand{\vecd}[1]{\overset{-\!-\!\rightharpoonup}{\vphantom{a}\smash {#1}}} \)\(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\)\(\newcommand{\AA}{\unicode[.8,0]{x212B}}\)

    Price impacts: Complements and substitutes

    The nature of complements and substitutes, defined in Chapter 4, can be further understood with the help of Figure 6.10. The new equilibrium E2 has been drawn so that the increase in the price of jazz results in more snowboarding—the quantity of S increases to S2 from S0. These goods are substitutes in this picture, because snowboarding increases in response to an increase in the price of jazz. If the new equilibrium E2 were at a point yielding a lower level of S than S0, we would conclude that they were complements.

    Cross-price elasticities

    Continuing with the same price increase in jazz, we could compute the percentage change in the quantity of snowboarding demanded as a result of the percentage change in the jazz price. In this example, the result would be a positive elasticity value, because the quantity change in snowboarding and the price change in jazz are both in the same direction, each being positive.

    Income impacts: Normal and inferior goods

    We know from Chapter 4 that the quantity demanded of a normal good increases in response to an income increase, whereas the quantity demanded of an inferior good declines. Clearly, both jazz and boarding are normal goods, as illustrated in Figure 6.10, because more of each one is demanded in response to the income increase from img209.png to img210.png. It would challenge the imagination to think that either of these goods might be inferior. But if J were to denote junky (inferior) goods and S super goods, we could envisage an equilibrium img34.png to the northwest of img145.png in response to an income increase, along the constraint img210.png; less J and more S would be consumed in response to the income increase.

    Policy: Income transfers and price subsidies

    Government policies that improve the purchasing power of low-income households come in two main forms: Pure income transfers and price subsidies. Social Assistance payments ("welfare") or Employment Insurance benefits, for example, provide an increase in income to the needy. Subsidies, on the other hand, enable individuals to purchase particular goods or services at a lower price—for example, rent or daycare subsidies.

    In contrast to taxes, which reduce the purchasing power of the consumer, subsidies and income transfers increase purchasing power. The impact of an income transfer, compared with a pure price subsidy, can be analyzed using Figures 6.11 and 6.12.

    Figure 6.11 Income transfer
    img211.png
    An increase in income due to a government transfer shifts the budget constraint from I1 to I2. This parallel shift increases the quantity consumed of the target good (daycare) and other goods, unless one is inferior.

    In Figure 6.11, an income transfer increases income from I1 to I2. The new equilibrium at E2 reflects an increase in utility, and an increase in the consumption of both daycare and other goods.

    Suppose now that a government program administrator decides that, while helping this individual to purchase more daycare accords with the intent of the transfer, she does not intend that government money should be used to purchase other goods. She therefore decides that a daycare subsidy program might better meet this objective than a pure income transfer.

    A daycare subsidy reduces the price of daycare and therefore rotates the budget constraint outwards around the intercept on the vertical axis. At the equilibrium in Figure 6.12, purchases of other goods change very little, and therefore most of the additional purchasing power is allocated to daycare.

    Figure 6.12 Price subsidy
    img212.png
    A subsidy to the targeted good, by reducing its price, rotates the budget constraint from I1 to I2. This induces the consumer to direct expenditure more towards daycare and less towards other goods than an income transfer that does not change the relative prices.

    Let us take the example one stage further. From the initial equilibrium img34.png in Figure 6.12, suppose that, instead of a subsidy that took the individual to img213.png, we gave an income transfer that enabled the consumer to purchase the combination img213.png. Such a transfer is represented in Figure 6.13 by a parallel outward shift of the budget constraint from img210.png to img214.png, going through the point img213.png. We now have a subsidy policy and an alternative income transfer policy, each permitting the same consumption bundle (img213.png). The interesting aspect of this pair of possibilities is that the income transfer will enable the consumer to attain a higher level of satisfaction—for example, at point img138.png —and will also induce her to consume more of the good on the vertical axis. The higher level of satisfaction comes about because the consumer has more latitude in allocating the additional real income.

    Application Box 6.3 Daycare subsidies in Quebec

    The Quebec provincial government subsidizes daycare heavily. In the public-sector network called the "Centres de la petite enfance", families can place their children in daycare for less than $10 per day, while families that use the private sector are permitted a generous tax allowance for their daycare costs. This policy is designed to enable households to limit the share of their income expended on daycare. It is described in Figure 6.13.

    The consequences of strong subsidization are not negligible: Excess demand, to such an extent that children are frequently placed on waiting lists for daycare places long before their parents intend to use the service. Annual subsidy costs amount to almost $2 billion per year. At the same time, it has been estimated that the policy has enabled many more parents to enter the workforce than otherwise would have.

    Figure 6.13 Subsidy-transfer comparison
    img215.png
    A price subsidy to the targeted good induces the individual to move from E1 to E2, facing a budget constraint I2. An income transfer that permits him to consume E2 is given by img216.png; but it also permits him to attain a higher level of satisfaction, denoted by img217.png on the indifference curve U3.

    The price of giving

    Imagine now that the good on the horizontal axis is charitable donations, rather than daycare, and the government decides that for every dollar given the individual will see a reduction in their income tax of 50 cents. This is equivalent to cutting the 'price' of donations in half, because a donation of one dollar now costs the individual half of that amount. Graphically the budget constraint rotates outward with the vertical intercept unchanged. Since donations now cost less the individual has increased spending power as a result of the price reduction for donations. The price reduction is designed to increase the attractiveness of donations to the utility maximizing consumer.


    This page titled 6.4: Applications of indifference analysis is shared under a CC BY-NC-SA 4.0 license and was authored, remixed, and/or curated by Douglas Curtis and Ian Irvine (Lyryx) via source content that was edited to the style and standards of the LibreTexts platform; a detailed edit history is available upon request.