Skip to main content
Social Sci LibreTexts

13.5: Education returns and quality

  • Page ID
    108447
  • \( \newcommand{\vecs}[1]{\overset { \scriptstyle \rightharpoonup} {\mathbf{#1}} } \) \( \newcommand{\vecd}[1]{\overset{-\!-\!\rightharpoonup}{\vphantom{a}\smash {#1}}} \)\(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\)\(\newcommand{\AA}{\unicode[.8,0]{x212B}}\)

    How can we be sure that further education really does generate the returns, in the form of higher future incomes, to justify the investment? For many years econometricians proposed that an extra year of schooling might offer a return in the region of 10% – quite a favourable return in comparison with what is frequently earned on physical capital. Doubters then asked if the econometric estimation might be subject to bias – what if the additional earnings of those with more education are simply attributable to the fact that it is the innately more capable individuals who both earn more and who have more schooling? And since we cannot observe who has more innate ability, how can we be sure that it is the education itself, rather than just differences in ability, that generate the extra income?

    This is a classical problem in inference: Does correlation imply causation? The short answer to this question is that education economists are convinced that the time invested in additional schooling does indeed produce additional rewards, even if it is equally true that individuals who are innately smarter do choose to invest in that way. Furthermore, it appears that the returns to graduate education are higher than the returns to undergraduate education.

    What can be said of the quality of different educational systems? Are educational institutions in different countries equally good at producing knowledgeable students? Or, viewed another way: Has a grade nine student in Canada the same skill set as a grade nine student in France or Hong Kong? An answer to this question is presented in Table 13.1, which contains results from the Program for International Student Assessment (PISA) – an international survey of 15-year old student abilities in mathematics, science and literacy. This particular table presents the results for a sample of the countries that were surveyed. The results indicate that Canadian students perform well in all three dimensions of the test.

    Table 13.1 Mean scores in PISA tests
    Country Math Science Reading
    Australia 494 510 503
    Austria 497 495 485
    Belgium 507 502 499
    Canada 516 528 527
    Denmark 511 502 500
    Finland 511 531 526
    France 493 495 499
    Germany 506 509 509
    Greece 454 455 467
    Hong Kong 548 523 527
    Ireland 504 503 521
    Italy 490 481 485
    Japan 532 538 516
    Korea 524 516 517
    Mexico 408 416 423
    New Zealand 495 513 509
    Norway 502 498 513
    Spain 486 493 496
    Sweden 494 493 500
    Switzerland 521 506 492
    Turkey 420 425 428
    United States 470 496 497
    United Kingdom 492 509 498

    An interesting paradox arises at this point: If productivity growth in Canada has lagged behind some other economies in recent decades, as many economists believe, how can this be explained if Canada produces many well-educated high-skill workers? The answer may be that there is a considerable time lag before high participation rates in third-level education and high quality make themselves felt on the national stage in the form of elevated productivity. The evidence suggests a good productivity future, in so far as it depends upon human capital. At the same time, if investment in human capital is not matched by investment in physical capital then the human capital may not be able to perform to its ability.


    This page titled 13.5: Education returns and quality is shared under a CC BY-NC-SA 4.0 license and was authored, remixed, and/or curated by Douglas Curtis and Ian Irvine (Lyryx) via source content that was edited to the style and standards of the LibreTexts platform; a detailed edit history is available upon request.