Skip to main content
Social Sci LibreTexts

5.1: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

  • Page ID
    11809
  • \( \newcommand{\vecs}[1]{\overset { \scriptstyle \rightharpoonup} {\mathbf{#1}} } \) \( \newcommand{\vecd}[1]{\overset{-\!-\!\rightharpoonup}{\vphantom{a}\smash {#1}}} \)\(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\)\(\newcommand{\AA}{\unicode[.8,0]{x212B}}\)

    The short run in macroeconomics is defined by assuming a specific set of conditions in the economy. These are:

    1. There are constant prices for factors of production, especially money wage rates for labour.
    2. The supply of labour, the stock of capital, and the state of technology are fixed.
    3. The money supply is also fixed.

    Short run: a time frame in which factor prices, supplies of factors of production, and technology are fixed by assumption.

    In the short run, changes in output involve changes in the employment of labour and in the use of plant and equipment, but these changes are not sustainable over longer time periods. Furthermore, because supplies of factor inputs and technology are fixed, there is no sustained growth in real GDP. We leave that topic for a later chapter.

    The national accounts we studied in Chapter 4 describe and measure economic activity in terms of an accounting framework used to measure aggregate expenditures, outputs, and incomes. But the accounting framework simply measures what has happened in the recent past. It does not explain the level of economic activity and prices or the reasons for changes in output and prices from time to time.

    For that we need an analytical framework that looks at cause and effect. An aggregate demand (AD) and aggregate supply (AS) model is such an analytical framework. It helps us understand the conditions that determine output and prices, and changes in output and prices over time.

    AD/AS model: a framework used ot explain the behaviour of real output and prices in the national economy.

    The short-run AD/AS model builds on the national accounts framework. Aggregate demand is the relationship between aggregate expenditure on final goods and services and the general price level. Real GDP by the expenditure approach measures this expenditure at the price level given by the GDP deflator. Aggregate supply is the relationship between the output of goods and services produced by business and the general price level. Real GDP by the income approach measures this output, and the corresponding real incomes. The price level is again the GDP deflator. National accounts tell us that, by definition, these measured outputs and incomes are equal. AD and AS functions describe expenditure plans, outputs, and prices using the national accounts framework. This distinction between measured and planned expenditure and output is important. Planned expenditure is the current output households and businesses would want to buy at different levels of income and price. Output is what businesses actually produce. Planned expenditure and the actual output produced by business may not be the same.

    Figure 5.1 gives us a first look at output, real income, and prices for a specific year using an aggregate demand and aggregate supply diagram. The price level as measured by the GDP deflator is measured on the vertical axis. Real output and income are measured on the horizontal axis. The point of intersection of the AD and AS lines shows that real output by the expenditure approach, Y0, is equal to real income by the income approach at the price level P0, as required by national accounts. It also shows planned aggregate expenditures equal to the current output of goods and services. However, we need to explain the aggregate demand and aggregate supply relationships indicated by the slopes and positions of the AD and AS lines in the diagram before we use the model to study output and prices.

    Screenshot 2019-03-04 at 21.52.30.png

    Figure 5.1: A Basic Aggregate Demand and Supply Model
    The AD and AS lines show planned expenditures on and output of final
    goods and services at different aggregate price levels all other conditions
    held constant
    . At the intersection of AD0 and AS0 planned expenditures on
    final goods and services are equal to real GDP at P0.

    Aggregate Demand (AD) is planned aggregate expenditure on final goods and services \((C + I + G + X - IM)\) at different price levels when all other conditions are constant. We will examine this relationship in detail in the chapters that follow. A downward sloping AD curve means the relationship between planned aggregate expenditure and the general price level is negative. A higher price level reduces the expenditures planned by households, businesses, and residents of other countries. Lower price levels increase those expenditure plans.

    Aggregate Demand: planned aggregate expenditure on final goods and services at different price levels, all other conditions remaining constant.

    Aggregate Supply (AS) is the output of final goods and services business produces at different price levels when other conditions are constant. As the upward sloping AS curve in Figure 5.1 assumes that the relationship between the quantity of goods and services produced and the price level is positive. Prices and output rise or fall together. We will examine this relationship in more detail below and in later chapters.

    Aggregate Supply: the output of final goods and services businesses would produce at different price levels, all other conditions held constant.

    Aggregate Demand

    Aggregate Demand and the market demand for an individual product are different. In our discussion of the market for an individual product in Chapter 3, demand is based on the assumptions that incomes and prices of other products are constant. Then a rise in the price of the product makes the product more expensive relative to income and relative to other products. As a result, people buy less of the product. Alternatively, if price falls people buy more.

    The link between the general price level and aggregate demand is different. We cannot assume constant incomes and prices of other products. In the aggregate economy a rise in the price level raises money incomes by an equal amount. A 10 percent rise in the general price level is also a 10 percent rise in money incomes. Changes in the price level do not make goods and services either more or less affordable, in terms of incomes. There is no direct price incentive to change aggregate expenditure.

    Furthermore, if prices of individual goods and services do not rise or fall in the same proportion as the general price level, the distribution of aggregate expenditure among goods and services may change without a change in aggregate expenditure. If, for example, the general price level is pushed up because oil and commodity prices rise, and expenditure on those products rises in the short run because there are no alternatives, expenditures on other goods and services fall. Aggregate expenditure is unchanged.

    As a result, we cannot explain the negative relationship between the general price level and aggregate expenditure as we would explain demand for an individual good or service. Nor can we simply add up all the demands for individual products and services to get aggregate demand. The assumptions of constant incomes and other product prices that underlie market demand do not hold in the aggregate. Different explanations are needed.

    Money and financial markets play key roles in the explanation of the price-quantity relationship in aggregate demand. The traditional AD function is based on a fixed nominal money supply and a demand for real money balances. The interplay between the supply of money balances and the demand for money balances in financial markets determine the interest rates and foreign exchange rates that are important to aggregate expenditure decisions. Chapters 8, 9 and 10 examine these financial markets and their effects on expenditure.

    In broad terms, changes in price levels change the supply and demand for money and other assets in financial markets. Change interest rates and foreign exchange rates follow. A rise in the price level causes a rise in interest rates that increases the cost of financing expenditures. It may also change the foreign exchange rate making imports cheaper relative to domestic products and exports less competitive in foreign markets, reducing net exports. In combination these changes reduce aggregate expenditure. The result is a negative relationship between the price level and aggregate expenditure and a negatively sloped AD curve.

    In Figure 5.2, the negatively sloped AD line shows planned aggregate expenditures at different price levels, on the assumption that the money supply and anything other than price that might affect expenditure plans are held constant. If the price level falls from P0 to P1, the movement along AD from A to B shows the negative relationship between planned aggregate expenditure and price. A rise in price would reduce planned expenditure as shown by moving up the AD curve.

    Screenshot 2019-03-04 at 22.14.14.png

    Figure 5.2: The Aggregate Demand Curve
    The AD curve shows planned expenditures at different aggregate price lev-
    els all things other than price held constant. A change in the price level
    causes movement along the AD curve as from A to B if the price falls from P0
    to P1.

    The position of the AD curve depends on all the conditions other than price that affect aggregate expenditure plans. We study these other conditions in detail in later chapters.

    Aggregate Supply

    Aggregate Supply (AS) is the output of final goods and services businesses would produce at different price levels. The aggregate supply curve is based on the following key assumptions:

    1. Prices of the factors of production—the money wage rate for labour in particular—are constant.
    2. The stock of capital equipment—the buildings and equipment used in the production process— and the technology of production are constant.

    From national accounts we know that the costs of production include labour costs, business and investment incomes and depreciation. Market prices depend on those costs per unit of output and the output and price setting decisions by producers. Aggregate supply is usually described as a positive relationship between quantities of goods and services businesses are willing to produce and prices. Higher outputs of final goods and services and higher prices go together.

    This relationship between aggregate output, costs and prices reflects two different market conditions on the supply side. In some markets, particularly those for commodities and standardized products, supply and demand in international markets establish price. Producers of those products are price takers. They decide how much labour and plant capacity to employ to produce based on market price.

    Broadly speaking, in these industries cost per unit of output are increasing with increasing output. Employing more labour and plant capacity means expanding into less productive land and natural resource inputs. Mining gold or extracting bitumen from oil sands are good examples. A rise in price justifies expanding the output of higher cost mines and oil wells. However, many raw material markets are like this including those for agricultural products, forestry products, base metals and natural gas. When market price changes these producers respond by changing their outputs.

    In other parts of the economy producers are price setters. Major manufacturing and service industries like auto producers, banks and wireless phone companies face market conditions that are different from those of commodity producers. They set prices based on costs of production and sales and profit targets, and supply the number of cars or bank services or cell phone accounts that are in demand at those prices.

    In these industries costs per unit of output are constant over a wide range of current outputs. Money wage rates are fixed, the capacity to produce output is flexible and productivity is constant. If demand for their product or service increases they can supply more by hiring more employees at existing wage rates and selling more output at existing prices. Industries like major manufacturing, retail services, financial services, hospitality services, and professional services are some examples. Output and changes in output are determined by demand.

    The upward-sloping aggregate supply curve in Figure 5.3 captures both market conditions to show the output producers are willing to produce and the price level. The aggregate supply curve is drawn based on the assumptions that money wage rates and all other conditions except price that might affect output decisions are constant. As we will see in later chapters, money wage rates and productivity are the most important of these conditions. They determine the position of the AS curve.

    Screenshot 2019-03-04 at 22.21.16.png

    Figure 5.3: The Aggregate Supply Curve
    The AS curve shows the relationship between price level and real GDP,
    assuming the prices of factors of production are constant. The position
    of the curve is determined by factor prices and productivity. The slope is
    determined by changes in costs of production and producer price decisions
    as output changes.

    The slope of the AS curve depends on changes in cost per unit of output and price changes if aggregate output changes. As a result it reflects the structure of industry. In Canada, for example Table 4.4 shows that about 70 percent of real GDP comes from service producing industries. Consequently we would expect a smaller positive slope in the AS curve than in Figure 5.3.

    In Figure 5.3, if price were P2 the AS curve shows that business would be willing to produce aggregate output Y2, which would generate an equal flow of real income. A rise in aggregate output from Y2 to Y3 would mean a rise in price to P3 to meet the increased costs and profits associated with output at this level. Changes in output or price, holding all other conditions constant, move the economy along the AS curve. Moving from point C to point D in the diagram shows this relationship.

    On the other hand, a change in any of the conditions assumed to be constant will shift the entire AS curve. A rise in money wage rates, for example, would increase labour costs per unit of output (W/Y) at every level of output. The AS curve would shift up vertically as prices rose in order to cover the increased unit labour costs.

    Equilibrium Real GDP and Price

    Aggregate demand and aggregate supply together determine equilibrium real GDP and the general price level. Figure 5.4 illustrates equilibrium. Aggregate demand is planned aggregate expenditure at different prices. Aggregate supply is aggregate output at different prices. The circular flow diagram and national accounts show how aggregate expenditure provides the flow of revenue business needs to cover its costs of production, and that those costs of production are income flows to households. When planned aggregate expenditure is equal to output, we have equilibrium real GDP. The revenues businesses receive from aggregate expenditure are just what they require to cover their costs, including expected profit. As long as conditions affecting expenditure and output plans are constant, business has no incentive to change output. This equilibrium between aggregate expenditure, outputs, and income and the general price level is illustrated by the intersection of the AD and AS curves in Figure 5.4.

    Equilibrium real GDP: AD=AS, planned expenditure equals current output and provides business revenues that cover costs including expected profit.


    Screenshot 2019-03-04 at 22.27.31.png

    Figure 5.4: Equilibrium Real GDP and Price
    The intersection of AD0 and AS0 gives equilibrium Y0 and P0 at point A.
    Any other Y such as Y1 or Y2 would result in unwanted changes in invento-
    ries
    and changes in output.

    To understand what equilibrium means we consider what would happen if the economy were not at point A in the diagram. Suppose, for example, business produced output and paid costs greater than Y0, as would be the case at point B on the AS curve. Output would be Y2, but planned expenditure at P1 is only Y1, less than business needs to cover its costs. Aggregate demand is lower than expected, output Y1Y2 is not sold. Costs of production are not recovered and unwanted inventories build up. In response, business would cut output, moving back to point A. Alternatively, if output were less than Y0 higher demand and unwanted reductions in inventories would provide strong incentives to increase output. Market conditions push the economy to equilibrium, the point where AD equals AS.

    The equilibrium determined by aggregate demand and aggregate supply at point A is the result of the economic conditions at a moment in time, and the expenditure and output decisions in the economy. It is a short-run equilibrium. The aggregate supply curve is based on the assumption that money wage rates, other factor prices, capital stock and technology are constant. However, any change in the conditions that affect expenditure and output plans would change the AD and AS curves and lead to a new short-run equilibrium real GDP and price.


    This page titled 5.1: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply is shared under a CC BY-NC-SA license and was authored, remixed, and/or curated by Douglas Curtis and Ian Irvine (Lyryx) .

    • Was this article helpful?