12.5: Substitution Effects
( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\)


selected template will load here
This action is not available.
( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\)
It would be a simpler world if an increase in the price of a good always entailed buying less of it. Alas, it isn’t so, as Figure 12.9 illustrates. In this figure, an increase in the price of Y causes the budget line to pivot around the intersection on the x-axis, since the amount of X that can be purchased hasn’t changed. In this case, the quantity y of Y demanded rises.
At first glance, this increase in the consumption of a good in response to a price increase sounds implausible, but there are examples where it makes sense. The primary example is leisure. As wages rise, the cost of leisure (forgone wages) rises. But as people feel wealthier, they choose to work fewer hours. The other examples given, which are hotly debated in the “tempest in a teapot” kind of way, involve people subsisting on a good like potatoes but occasionally buying meat. When the price of potatoes rises, they can no longer afford meat and buy even more potatoes than before.
Thus, the logical starting point on substitution—what happens to the demand for a good when the price of that good increases—does not lead to a useful theory. As a result, economists have devised an alternative approach based on the following logic. An increase in the price of a good is really a composition of two effects: an increase in the relative price of the good and a decrease in the purchasing power of money. As a result, it is useful to examine these two effects separately. The substitution effect considers the change in the relative price, with a sufficient change in income to keep the consumer on the same utility isoquant.Some authors instead change the income enough to make the old bundle affordable. This approach has the virtue of being readily computed, but the disadvantage is that the substitution effect winds up increasing the utility of the consumer. Overall the present approach is more economical for most purposes. The income effect changes only income.
Figure 12.10 Substitution effect
We can readily see that the substitution effect of a price increase in Y is to decrease the consumption of Y and increase the consumption of X.To construct a formal proof, first show that if pY rises and y rises, holding utility constant, the initial choice prior to the price increase is feasible after the price increase. Use this to conclude that, after the price increase, it is possible to have strictly more of both goods, contradicting the hypothesis that utility was held constant. The income effect is the change in consumption resulting from the change in income. The effect of any change in price can be decomposed into the substitution effect, which holds utility constant while changing and the income effect, which adjusts for the loss of purchasing power arising from the price increase.
Example (Cobb-Douglas): Recall that the Cobb-Douglas utility comes in the form u( x,y )= x α y 1−α . Solving for x, y we obtain
x=aMpX, y=(1−a)MpY
and
u(x,y)=aa(1−a)1−aMpXapY1−a
Thus, consider a multiplicative increase Δ in pY that is, multiplying pY by Δ > 1. In order to leave the utility constant, M must rise by Δ1 –α. Thus, x rises by the factor Δ1 –α and y falls by the factor Δ–α < 1. This is the substitution effect.
What is the substitution effect of a small change in the price pY for any given utility function, not necessarily Cobb-Douglas? To address this question, it is helpful to introduce some notation. We will subscript the utility to indicate partial derivative; that is,
u1=∂u∂x, u2=∂u∂y.
Note that, by the definition of the substitution effect, we are holding the utility constant, so u(x, y) is being held constant. This means, locally, that 0=du= u 1 dx+ u 2 dy. Writing dx for an unknown infinitesimal change in x can be put on a formal basis. The easiest way to do so is to think of dx as representing the derivative of x with respect to a parameter, which will be pY.
In addition, we have M=pXx+pYy, so dM=pXdx+pYdy+ydpY.
Finally, we have the optimality condition p X p Y = ∂u ∂x ∂u ∂y , which is convenient to write as p X u 2 = p Y u 1 . Differentiating this equation, and lettingu 11 = ∂ 2 u (∂x) 2 , u 12 = ∂ 2 u ∂x∂y , and u 22 = ∂ 2 u (∂y) 2 ,we havep X ( u 12 dx+ u 22 dy)= u 1 d p Y + p Y ( u 11 dx+ u 12 dy).
For a given dpY, we now have three equations in three unknowns: dx, dy, and dM. However, dM only appears in one of the three. Thus, the effect of a price change on x and y can be solved by solving two equations: 0= u 1 dx+ u 2 dy and p X ( u 12 dx+ u 22 dy)= u 1 d p Y + p Y ( u 11 dx+ u 12 dy) for the two unknowns, dx and dy. This is straightforward and yields
dxd pY=−pYu1p×2u11+2pXpYu12+pY2u22dydpY=pYu2p×2u11+2pXpYu12+pY2u22
These equations imply that x rises and y falls.This is a consequence of the fact that p X 2 u 11 +2 p X p Y u 12 + p Y 2 u 22 <0 , which follows from the already stated second-order condition for a maximum of utility. We immediately see that
dy dpYdxdpY=−u1u2=−pXpY
Thus, the change in (x, y ) follows the budget line locally. (This is purely a consequence of holding utility constant.)
To complete the thought while we are embroiled in these derivatives, note that p×u2=pY u 1 implies that pXdx+pYdy=0
Thus, the amount of money necessary to compensate the consumer for the price increase, keeping utility constant, can be calculated from our third equation:
dM=pXdx+pY dy +ydpY=ydpY
The amount of income necessary to ensure that the consumer makes no losses from a price increase in Y is the amount that lets him or her buy the bundle that he or she originally purchased; that is, the increase in the amount of money is precisely the amount needed to cover the increased price of y. This shows that locally there is no difference between a substitution effect that keeps utility constant (which is what we explored) and one that provides sufficient income to permit purchasing the previously purchased consumption bundle, at least when small changes in prices are contemplated.