Skip to main content
Social Sci LibreTexts

15.7: Peak-load Pricing

  • Page ID
    47421
    • Anonymous
    • LibreTexts
    \( \newcommand{\vecs}[1]{\overset { \scriptstyle \rightharpoonup} {\mathbf{#1}} } \) \( \newcommand{\vecd}[1]{\overset{-\!-\!\rightharpoonup}{\vphantom{a}\smash {#1}}} \)\(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \(\newcommand{\id}{\mathrm{id}}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\) \( \newcommand{\kernel}{\mathrm{null}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\range}{\mathrm{range}\,}\) \( \newcommand{\RealPart}{\mathrm{Re}}\) \( \newcommand{\ImaginaryPart}{\mathrm{Im}}\) \( \newcommand{\Argument}{\mathrm{Arg}}\) \( \newcommand{\norm}[1]{\| #1 \|}\) \( \newcommand{\inner}[2]{\langle #1, #2 \rangle}\) \( \newcommand{\Span}{\mathrm{span}}\)\(\newcommand{\AA}{\unicode[.8,0]{x212B}}\)

    Learning Objectives
    • How do monopolies respond to predictable cost fluctuation as it arises in electricity and hotel markets?

    Fluctuations in demand often require holding capacity, which is used only a fraction of the time. Hotels have off-seasons when most rooms are empty. Electric power plants are designed to handle peak demand, usually on hot summer days, with some of the capacity standing idle on other days. Demand for transatlantic airline flights is much higher in the summer than during the rest of the year. All of these examples have the similarity that an amount of capacity—hotel space, airplane seats, electricity generation—will be used over and over, which means that it is used in both high demand and low demand states. How should prices be set when demand fluctuates? This question can be reformulated as to how to allocate the cost of capacity across several time periods when demand systematically fluctuates.

    Consider a firm that experiences two costs: a capacity cost and a marginal cost. How should capacity be priced? This issue applies to a wide variety of industries, including pipelines, airlines, telephone networks, construction, electricity, highways, and the Internet.

    The basic peak-load pricing problem, pioneered by Marcel Boiteux (1922– ), considers two periods. The firm’s profits are given by

    \begin{equation}π= p 1 q 1 + p 2 q 2 −β max { q 1 , q 2 }−mc( q 1 + q 2 ).\end{equation}

    Setting price equal to marginal cost is not sustainable because a firm selling with price equal to marginal cost would not earn a return on the capacity, and thus would lose money and go out of business. Consequently, a capacity charge is necessary. The question of peak-load pricing is how the capacity charge should be allocated. This question is not trivial because some of the capacity is used in both periods.

    For the sake of simplicity, we will assume that demands are independent; that is, q1 is independent of p2, and vice versa. This assumption is often unrealistic, and generalizing it actually doesn’t complicate the problem too much. The primary complication is in computing the social welfare when demands are functions of two prices. Independence is a convenient starting point.

    Social welfare is \(\begin{equation}W= ∫ 0 q 1 p 1 (x)dx + ∫ 0 q 2 p 2 (x)dx −β max { q 1 , q 2 }−mc( q 1 + q 2 ).\end{equation}\)

    The Ramsey problem is to maximize W subject to a minimum profit condition. A technique for accomplishing this maximization is to instead maximize L = W + λπ.

    By varying λ, we vary the importance of profits to the maximization problem, which will increase the profit level in the solution as λ increases. Thus, the correct solution to the constrained maximization problem is the outcome of the maximization of L, for some value of λ.

    A useful notation is 1A, which is known as the indicator function of the set A. This is a function that is 1 when A is true, and zero otherwise. Using this notation, the first-order condition for the maximization of L is

    \begin{equation}0= ∂L ∂ q 1 = p 1 ( q q )−β 1 q 1 ≥ q 2 −mc+λ( p 1 ( q q )+ q 1 p 1 ′ ( q 1 )−β 1 q 1 ≥ q 2 −mc ) or p 1 ( q 1 )−β 1 q 1 ≥ q 2 −mc p 1 = λ λ+1 1 ε 1 \end{equation},

    where 1 q 1 ≥ q 2 is the characteristic function of the event q1 ≥ q2. Similarly, \(\begin{equation}p 2 ( q 2 )−β 1 q 1 ≤ q 2 −mc p 2 = λ λ+1 1 ε 2\end{equation}\). Note as before that λ → ∞ yields the monopoly solution.

    There are two potential types of solutions. Let the demand for Good 1 exceed the demand for Good 2. Either q1 > q2, or the two are equal.

    Case 1 (q1 > q2):

    \begin{equation}\text { p } 1(q 1)-\beta-m c p 1=\lambda \lambda+11 \varepsilon 1 \text { and } p 2(q 2)-m c p 2=\lambda \lambda+11 \varepsilon 2\end{equation}

    In Case 1, with all of the capacity charge allocated to Good 1, quantity for Good 1 still exceeds quantity for Good 2. Thus, the peak period for Good 1 is an extreme peak. In contrast, Case 2 arises when assigning the capacity charge to Good 1 would reverse the peak—assigning all of the capacity charge to Good 1 would make Period 2 the peak.

    Case 2 (q1 = q2):

    The profit equation can be written \(\begin{equation}p_{1}(q)-m c+p_{2}(q)-m c=\beta\end{equation}\). This equation determines q, and prices are determined from demand.

    The major conclusion from peak-load pricing is that either the entire cost of capacity is allocated to the peak period or there is no peak period, in the sense that the two periods have the same quantity demanded given the prices. That is, either the prices equalize the quantity demanded or the prices impose the entire cost of capacity only on one peak period.

    Moreover, the price (or, more properly, the markup over marginal cost) is proportional to the inverse of the elasticity, which is known as Ramsey pricing.

    Key Takeaways

    • Fluctuations in demand often require holding capacity, which is used only a fraction of the time. Peak-load pricing allocates the cost of capacity across several time periods when demand systematically fluctuates.
    • Important industries with peak-load problems include pipelines, airlines, telephone networks, construction, electricity, highways, and the Internet.
    • Under efficient peak-load pricing, either the prices equalize the quantity demanded, or the prices impose the entire cost of capacity only on one peak period. Moreover, the markup over marginal cost is proportional to the inverse of the elasticity.

    EXERCISE

    1. For each of the following items, state whether you would expect peak-load pricing to equalize the quantity demanded across periods or impose the entire cost of capacity on the peak period. Explain why.
      1. Hotels in Miami
      2. Electricity

    This page titled 15.7: Peak-load Pricing is shared under a CC BY-NC-SA 3.0 license and was authored, remixed, and/or curated by Anonymous via source content that was edited to the style and standards of the LibreTexts platform; a detailed edit history is available upon request.